New IMF Working Paper Models Impact of Oil Limits on the Economy

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) recently issued a new working paper called “The Future of Oil: Geology versus Technology” (free PDF), which should be of interest to people who are following “peak oil” issues. This is a research paper that is being published to elicit comments and debate; it does not necessarily represent IMF views or policy.

The paper considers two different approaches for modeling future oil supply:

  1. The economic/technological approach, used by the US Energy Information Administration (EIA) and others, and
  2. The geological view, used in peak oil forecasts, such as forecasts made by Colin Campbell and forecasts made using Hubbert Linearization.

The analysis in the IMF Working Paper shows that neither approach has worked perfectly, but in recent years, forecasts of oil supply using the geological view have tended to be closer than those using the economic/technological approach.  Since neither model works perfectly, the new paper takes a middle ground: it sets up a model of oil supply where the amount of oil produced is influenced by a combination of (1) geological depletion and (2) price levels.

This blended model fits recent production amounts and recent price trends far better than traditional models. The forecasts it gives are concerning though.  The new model indicates that (1) oil supply in the future will not rise nearly as rapidly as in the pre-2005 period and (2) oil prices are likely to nearly double in “real” (inflation-adjusted) terms by 2020. The world economy will be in uncharted territory if this happens.

It seems to me that this new model is a real step forward in looking at oil supply and the economy. The model, as it is today, points out a definite problem area (namely, the likelihood of oil high prices, if growth in oil production continues to be constrained below pre-2005 rates of increase). The researchers also raise good questions for further analysis.

At the same time, I am doubtful that the world GDP forecast of the new model is really right–it seems too high. The questions the authors raise point in this direction as well. Below the fold, I discuss the model, its indications, and some shortcomings I see. 

The Two Models

Economic /Technological Approach. With the economic/ technological approach, the assumption is made that high oil prices will encourage substitution and/or new oil production. Because of this, high oil prices are not expected to persist. Instead, the most important consideration in determining future oil supply is the level of future demand. The level of future demand, in turn, is primarily driven by  anticipated GDP growth, since world GDP growth and world oil production growth tend to be highly correlated.

In effect, models of this type assume that whatever oil supply is needed will be available; they don’t consider the possibility that geological considerations may limit oil supply over the long term. As an example of how well these models have worked for prediction, the paper shows a graph of historical EIA forecasts (Figure 1, below).

Figure 1. Graph showing that oil production forecasts by the US Energy Information Administration have been revised downward, year after year, from paper.

Each year, EIA’s forecasts have been adjusted downward, because actual oil supply growth was lower than forecast.

Models Based on the Geological View. The paper considers forecasts of oil supply such as those of Colin Campbell (shown in ASPO-Ireland Newsletters) and forecasts based on Hubbert Linearization to be models based on the Geological View. The paper observes that forecasts of oil supply based on geological view have tended to be too low, but not by as big a margin as those made using the economic/technological approach. As an example, it gives the following graph of changes in forecasts by Colin Campbell.

Figure 2. Colin Campbell Forecasts of Future Oil Supply, from paper.

A review of the two methods by the IMF group indicates that neither works precisely as hoped, but each has some validity. While oil production did not rise as fast as the economic/technological view would predict, higher oil prices have allowed oil production to stay on more or less a plateau after 2005, rather than declining as predicted by geological methods. The new model in the IMF Working Paper combines indications from both points of view, using an approach that allows them to estimate the relative contribution of geological impacts vs higher prices.

How the Two Methods are Combined

The oil supply equation in the new model is set up so that there are two different ways that the forecast oil supply can change. There is a downward tug from oil depletion at the same time that there is an upward tug from oil prices. It is expected that in the short run, high prices will get producers to utilize spare capacity, and over a longer period (estimated at 4 to 6 years), it will get producers to add new capacity. I will not try to explain all the variables and coefficients, but the blended supply equation is

Figure 3. Oil Supply Equation

In the above equation, qt is the quantity of oil produced in year t and Qt is the cumulative quantity produced in year t, so the ratio qt / Qt produces the familiar downward-sloping line one sees in charts used for Hubbert Linearization. The first two terms to the right of the equal sign are the ones based on the geological approach to depletion. The later terms depend on pt, which is price of oil at the time “t”. Adding the  pt terms tends to raise the line at later periods so it does not slope downward as quickly as if depletion were the only factor affecting the relationship.

Growth Rate of GDP

In the model, high oil prices have some impact on GDP, but as we will see in Figure 5, below, not very much. There are two places in modeling GDP where high  oil prices come into play. The first is in the Potential Growth Rate of GDP. According to the paper,

The growth rate of potential world GDP is specified as fluctuating around an exogenous long-run trend, with oil price changes making the fluctuations more severe. Oil prices are allowed to have persistent but not permanent effects on the growth rate of GDP. . . The estimated steady state world potential growth rate of potential GDP equals four percent. The average annual growth rate of real oil prices, which is the growth in oil prices at which the model assumes zero effect of oil prices on output growth, is seven percent. The results indicate that an oil price growth that is higher than that historical average has a small but significant negative effect on the growth rate of potential. [emphasis added]

Interesting–the model assumes real oil price growth of 7% per year has no impact growth rate of GDP. Perhaps this is supposed to be picked up by the second place where high oil prices come into forecasting GDP, called Output Gap. This is an excerpt from what the paper says about Output Gap:

Apart from allowing for an effect of higher oil prices on the growth rate of potential output, the model also allows for the possibility that higher oil prices can cause fluctuations in the amount of excess demand in the economy. . . . Similar to the equation for potential, the coefficient estimates show that high oil prices have a small but significant negative effect on excess demand, and that this effect is highly persistent.

Model Output

When all is said and done, what does the IMF model forecast?

Figure 4. Oil Output Forecast with Error Bands, (in gigabarrels per year), from report.

The forecast for future world oil supply, shown in Figure 4 above, is similar to EIA’s most recent forecast of world oil supply (but lower than earlier EIA estimates). Oil supply is expected to rise a 0.9% per year. An alternate tighter oil supply forecast is given as well.

The forecast for world GDP growth (shown in Figure 5 below) is not too much different from standard estimates, either. The point forecast is about four percent per year.

Figure 5. World GDP (in logs) forecast with error bands, with 2011 world GDP normalized to 1.00, from report.

The thing that is different in this analysis is oil prices (in inflation adjusted dollars). Forecast oil prices are expected to be much higher that what the EIA is estimating.

Figure 6. Oil price forecast with error bands (in 2011 Real $) from report.

The report points out that these high oil prices are a real concern. The report says:

The predicted average annual growth rates of oil output are well below the historical forecasts of EIA, but above the forecasts of proponents of the geological view. . . . However, this projected positive trend in oil production comes at a steep cost, because the model finds that it requires a large increase in the real price of oil, which would have to nearly double over the coming decade to maintain an output expansion that is modest in historical terms. Such prices would far exceed even the highest prices seen in 2008, which according to Hamilton (2009) may have played an important roll in driving the world economy into a deep recession.

Need for Enhancements /Areas of Concern Pointed Out by Authors of Paper

The authors raise of the IMF Working Paper raise the following issues:

1. Impact of high oil prices on GDP growth. The expected impact of a continued rise in oil prices on forecast GDP is small, according to the model as constructed. Perhaps the relationship should be non-linear (convex) instead of linear. More generally, what is the importance of the availability of oil inputs for continued overall GDP growth? The report mentions studies showing the close connection between energy growth and GDP growth, such as by Ayers and Warr.

2. Substitutability for oil. What is the substitutability between oil and other factors of production? Is it reasonable to assume that elasticities of substitution will become greater over time? Or is there a possibility that there are limits to the extent of substitutability of machines and labor for energy?

3. Is there a pain barrier? At some point, does the effect of high oil prices on the economy change, and become much worse?

4. Independence of Technology from Fossil Fuel Availability. Perhaps a reduction in fossil fuel availability will negatively affect the availability of future technology improvements since, for example, it takes fossil fuels to make new more efficient cars. This has not been reflected in the model.

5. Smaller Amounts of “Spare” Oil Capacity Available in the Future. The model reflects amounts of OPEC spare oil production capacity available in the past. In the future, less spare production capacity seems likely.

My Comments on the Paper

The IMF is to be commended on putting together this analysis. To me, the big step forward is that questions about the impact of geological depletion of oil on the economy are starting to be addressed. The fact that the paper also points out the level to which oil prices will need to rise, if oil production is to rise at 0.9% a year between now and 2020, is important as well.

Some of the issues I see that aren’t addressed in the paper:

1. Factors underlying world long term growth rate, other than energy. It would seem to me that there are a number of factors which have permitted long term world economic growth, over and above the economic growth enabled by fossil fuels. Some of the following seem to be diminishing in importance, so perhaps the forecast of a 4% world GDP growth rate going forward is too high, apart from oil supply issues:

a. Trend Toward Globalization. The trend toward globalization has allowed greater synergies to occur, and thus has contributed to world GDP growth. The trend toward globalization started over 4,000 years ago, with trade from northwest India to the Mediterranean region (Chew). In recent years, we seem to be  approaching a maximum level of world globalization. In fact, higher price of oil has been raised as an issue cutting back on trade of bulky, low valued items (Rubin). Higher cost of oil may also have an adverse impact of commercial airline flights for international companies to oversee their distant operations, because the costs of these flights is now supported by a large number of international tourists, and this international tourist trade may dry up. Thus, the trend toward globalization that has been supporting world GDP growth in the past may not persist, and may even reverse.

b. Growth in Education. Part of what has supported world GDP growth is likely growth in education, since literate workers are better able to use technology. There is evidence that the advanced economies are now plateauing in terms of educational level of new workers, relative to the existing work force. Even less advanced economies, such as China, are showing much higher levels of literacy. (See this post). To the extent that educational levels are reaching a plateau, the “boost” to historical GDP rates that came from this factor can be expected to be lessened.

c. Growth in Debt. GDP growth is enabled by debt growth. Consumers are able to purchase more goods and services, with increased levels of debt; businesses are able to increase their investment in new plants and equipment through more debt; and governments are able to undertake the development of new construction, roads, and other development, through the addition of more debt. But we seem to be reaching limits on debt growth. Theory also suggests that higher levels of debt are enabled by higher economic growth rates (Tverberg). Governments have been aware that increased borrowing can be used to pump up economic growth, but limits are being reached on the amount of debt that can be added. To the extent that debt fails to grow as quickly in the future as it has in the past, this can be expected to have an adverse impact on world GDP growth rates.

d. Quantitative Easing and Extraordinarily Low Interest Rates. An argument can be made that GDP growth of advanced economies in recent years has been held up by quantitative easing and extraordinarily low interest rates. These would seem to be a temporary fixes that cannot be continued long-term. If this is the case, world GDP rates can be expected to be lower in the future, regardless of oil supply growth.

2. Limits on Substitutability of Other Fossil Fuels for Oil. The paper does not address the issue of whether there are limits of substitutability of other fossil fuels for oil. Stationary (as opposed to transportation) uses of oil have been substituting away from oil for years. There are millions of vehicles and other machines that use oil currently in operation. There will be a high cost in replacing these before the end of their normal lifetimes. Also, significant fossil fuels will be required for making vehicles and supporting infrastructure that use another fossil fuel source.

3. Limits on Capital Available for New Investment in Substitutes for Oil, and in New Oil Production. In recent years, we have made heavy use of debt financing for new investment. Government subsidies have also been used. To the extent that debt financing and government subsidies are less available, less investment can be expected in the future.

4. Impact of High Oil Prices on Diverse Parts of the Economy, Not Reflected in the Model. For example, prices of homes may be affected by high oil prices. People with less discretionary income are less likely to “trade up” to a more expensive homes, so high oil prices seem to be one of the reasons for the decline in home prices (Tverberg). Lower home prices affect ability of homeowners to borrow against the value of their homes for new purchases, so affect GDP, apart from oil price’s direct impact on the number of new homes built.

5. Which comes first: Oil Growth or Economic Growth? The assumption in the model is that GDP growth drives oil growth. While this is true, it is to some extent a “chicken” and “egg” situation. Perhaps the availability of inexpensive oil and other fossil fuels is one of the main drivers of economic growth (in addition to the other drivers I mention in the subparts of Item 1 above). Perhaps the cycle is started by the availability of cheap fossil fuels for industrial use and continued by the increased demand to which this growth gives rise.

* * *

I appreciate the work that has been done by the IMF in putting together this model and look forward to seeing further enhancements to the model. The work that has been done and the questions that are being raised are important ones.

I expect that commenters to this post will be able to point out other plusses and minuses of the model. The report itself is very interesting. Again, it can be found at The Future of Oil: Geology versus Technology.

About Gail Tverberg

My name is Gail Tverberg. I am an actuary interested in finite world issues - oil depletion, natural gas depletion, water shortages, and climate change. Oil limits look very different from what most expect, with high prices leading to recession, and low prices leading to financial problems for oil producers and for oil exporting countries. We are really dealing with a physics problem that affects many parts of the economy at once, including wages and the financial system. I try to look at the overall problem.
This entry was posted in Financial Implications, News Related Post and tagged , , , , . Bookmark the permalink.

119 Responses to New IMF Working Paper Models Impact of Oil Limits on the Economy

  1. Pingback: New IMF Working Paper Models Impact of Oil Limits on the Economy »

  2. Pingback: IMF Working Paper predicts doubling of oil prices in coming decade « 3E Intelligence

  3. Pingback: IMF zoekt naar olie in de kristallen bol « Cassandraclub

  4. Pingback: IMF zoekt naar olie in een kristallen bol | Sargasso

  5. Steven Kopits says:

    I have run my own set of numbers, and they’re actually not that different than those of the IMF. But a 7% annual increase in price isn’t that much. Remember, from 2003-2008, the oil price was increasing at 25% per year. The IMF’s analysis suggests the oil party is largely over, believe it or not.

    Now, that’s not the interesting part. The interesting part is that the oil project approval threshold price has been rising at 18% per annum for the last several years. My analysis (consistent with the IMF) suggests that the approval threshold in the future will be unable to rise faster than the oil price, that is, 7%.

    What are the implications for oil production? Well, it’s possible that current approval thresholds–$98 Brent for 2012 according to the Barclays Dec. E&P Survey–is high enough for many projects well into the future. This would be the Tierney perspective: There is a much larger resource just beyond the current price level. In this case, a slower growing oil price is no obstacle to increased oil production. What evidence do we have of this assertion? Crude oil production really hasn’t picked up much, so higher oil prices to date have not coincided with higher oil production. The exception is, of course, shale/tight oil production, some of which is quite economical at, say, $80. So the “bigger resource” thesis could be true, if we allow for time lags to bring projects to market, but it doesn’t exactly hit one over the head by contrast with, for example, various types of natural gas opportunities.

    Alternatively, the slower growing oil price could cap oil E&P opportunities, ie, without a rapidly increasing oil price, the oil companies find fewer and fewer projects which meet economic criteria. In this case, we might expect depletion to overtake incremental production–and this in turn would lead to peak oil–a Chris Skrebowski economic peak oil, not a Hubbert geological peak oil. What evidence do we have of this? Well, the crude oil supply stalled out in 2005, and 2011 crude production was only 300 kbpd higher. So price signals seemed largely ineffective during this period. Secondly, we just don’t have a huge backlog of big oil projects rushing to market. It’s not apparent that oil prices will lead to massive increases in oil production based on visible projects. Also, we have a big production miss by Exxon in Q1. In any event, depletion and incremental production seem pretty finely balanced as it is. If future price increases will be less, then there’s a pretty good chance the number of qualifying projects for the oil companies will begin to taper off. This seems the more likely outcome to me, allowing that both above-ground considerations and technology could influence this outcome.

    If so, when does this occur? The current Brent price is $112, the threshold price, $98. In this environment, how much do we think the oil companies will increase their threshold price this year? Unless oil prices recover strongly in H2 (and I don’t think they will), then the threshold might rise to say, $105-107, which is 7-9% higher than last year. Thus, there is a good chance we are on the 7% threshold already. If that’s so, and oil E&P costs continue to rise, then the oil companies will face diminishing opportunities already in 2013. Put another way, we could see economic peak oil as soon as next year.

    • Steve,

      Those are interesting insights. Thanks for sharing them. There are certainly quite a few different ways we could get to a downturn in production. I would agree with you with respect to the oil price for 2012 likely not averaging very high, with all of the financial problems right now. At some point, the lack of rise in oil prices (or perhaps an absolute decrease in prices, due to worldwide recession), seems likely to stifle world oil production.

      • Don Millman says:

        Gail,
        As usual, your economic and financial analysis is 100% correct, and I agree with all your economic and financial prognostications. Perhaps we differ in one part of our view of the financial future over the next five or ten or twenty years. IMHO, when the strain of debt becomes intolerable all the central banks all over the world will greatly and quickly expand the M2 money supply. I expect inflation rates of at least 10% per year, and perhaps higher rates. Note that at a compound rate of growth an inflation rate of 10%/year, the value of the dollar would be cut in half in 7.2 years. Thus the burden of mortage debt, national debt, and student debt could be cut in half in just 7.2 years. We might get hyperinflation, but I think double digit inflation is much more likely in the U.S. over the next twenty years.

        Why will we be unlikely to have hyperinflation in the U.S. over the next ten to twenty years? For one and only one reason: Every single one of the governors of the U.S. Federal Reserve system knows all about hyperinflation–its causes and cures. To a large extent, the Fed has the power not to be pressured by Congress or the President. The Fed does its best to use monetary policy to stabilize the economy. However, the late great economist, Milton Friedman, made a very strong case that by using its own discretion rather than strict rules the Fed has actually had a strongly destabilized the U.S. economy, going back at least to the 1920. Indeed, Friedman wanted to abolish the Fed and in its place do monetary policy strictly according to rules that would tend to
        1. get inflation rates down to about 0% over the years,
        2. prevent inflationary bubbles and subsequent crashes like we have recently seen in real estate.

        I agree with Friedman on this point.

  6. Mark Collet says:

    How the philosopher’s stone transmutes models into unconventional oil:
    Campbell Balance
    Gba Total Conventional Unconventional
    IMF Actual 2010 31 23 9
    IMF Min 2021 31 19 12
    IMF Max 2021 37 19 18

  7. Mark Collet says:

    I’ll try again.
    How the philosopher’s stone transmutes Campbell Fig.3 and IMF model Fig.10 into unconventional oil:
    ……………………………………..Campbell…………….Balance
    Gba.(Mbd x 365)…Total…..Conventional……Unconventional
    IMF 2010 Actual…….31……………….23……………………..9
    IMF 2021 Minimum…31……………….19……………………12
    IMF 2021 Maximum..37………………..19……………………18

  8. las artes says:

    To gauge the impact of the recent rise in oil prices, I used a dynamic macroeconomic model of the U.S. economy. By raising oil prices from $95 to $105 in the simulation, we gain an estimate of the broader impacts on the U.S. economy. The results show a relatively small impact. A $10 oil price increase, sustained over four quarters, decreases real GDP growth by 0.2 percentage point. The impact on consumption spending is twice as large: 0.4 percent. Investment growth falls by just 0.2 percent as IT equipment and software aren’t as sensitive to rising oil prices. Higher oil prices would reduce growth in non-oil-producing developing countries such as China and India, cutting U.S. export growth by 0.3 percent. The impact on exports isn’t as large as you might anticipate, since large oil-producing countries (especially Canada and Mexico) eventually import more from the U.S. These impacts are shown in the table below.

  9. Pingback: IMF team warns of global economy entering uncharted territory with US$ 180 a barrel in 2021

  10. donsailorman says:

    I do not know how “donsailorman” came to this website. I use “donsailorman” on theoildrum.com, but on ourfiniteworld.com I use my genuine name, Don Millman.

    • David Harney says:

      Hi Don,

      Welcome to the mysteries and foibles of WordPress! Whether I’m Bicycle Dave or David Harney seems to depend on the phases of the moon – otherwise I can’t find a correlation.

      I’ve tried to email WordPress about this issue but they have never replied.

      • donsailorman says:

        I tried to make a reply to you here, but some glitch put the comment way upthread after one of your other comments. Perhaps it is a glitch related using my “Don Sailorman” TOD name instead of my genuine one. As long as we have had computers we have had glitches. Probably this statement will be true indefintely into future–as long as we have computers.

        • David Harney says:

          Hi Don,

          Caught the message above – you certainly have a good memory! I was just up in the attic the other day and recalled our conversation about the Raleigh.

          My advice is to switch to a recumbent bike sooner than later. I waited until I was 65; however, by then I had developed some pretty nasty neck issues from too many years on the drop handle bars. My single recumbent is a Volae (http://www.hostelshoppe.com/images/products/lb_09vol_club.jpg). I’ve been riding the Volae for 8 years now and still love the bike. I’ve taken it to Ireland several times and ridden the MS 150 here in Wisconsin every year since I got it. And, this after I was about to give up cycling due to all my aches and pains on a diamond frame bike!

          As you can see from my “Gravatar” thing, my wife and I ride a recumbent trike. Trikes are great and that will be my next step for a single bike if I can no longer manage the Volae. Good to see you younger fellows are still riding your bike 🙂

          • donsailorman says:

            Thank you for the link. However, I think I will keep my folding Brompton for now. Why? Because it folds up into a suitcase and you just pay regular luggage rates to take it along on an airplane ticket. Also, it is only eleven years old and has only about 15,000 miles on it. Generally I aim for 25,000 miles on a bike before I replace it with a newer one. My 1985 Schwinn 5 speed heavy Cruiser Bike–the most comfortable bike I have ever owned–had one rebuild around 25,000 miles, and then I kept riding it until roughly 40,000 miles.
            Also I keep my cars going a long time ago. Currently my 1993 Audi station wagon has 244,000 miles on it, and it is in excellent shape. My Audi mechanic (from whom I bought the car back in 2,001) thinks it will very likely go to 350,000 miles with repair bills averaging about $500 per year.

            I get emotionally attached to my favorite bikes and cars and hate to give them up.

            From both good genes and steady leg exercise on bike or on foot I am blessed with unusually strong legs, and I’ve never had any back problems. I can still easily ride for two hours without stopping at my steady 12 m.p.h. pace, then take a break of half an our to an hour and ride back the 24 miles to get home. Much of my stamina comes from still playing singles men’s tennis with players who are much younger than I am.

            I’ll bet this reply comes up under “Don Sailorman.”

Comments are closed.